Skip to main content

The Public Good


There exists a game by which the famed economist Paul Samuelson, with support from fellow economist Amartya Sen, contends that the self-interested economic man is revealed to be a rational fool. The game here is one in which eight participants individually enter a room with five one-dollar bills — that is, each individual holds in his or her possession five one-dollar bills. 

Let us suspend for a moment, and in doing so indulge the position of imprudent economists, any curiosity regarding the source of these five-dollar windfalls to conveniently afford the game the convenient assumption that some form of recognized labor, or sacrifice, enabled their acquisition and their utility as money.

The participants are then informed that their anonymous donations to the envelope of “public good” will be doubled then distributed evenly amongst the participants. 

The prediction in this game, as forecasted by the aforementioned economists, is that the individual, facing an 80% loss on his individual dollar contribution if no other participant joins him, will merely forego the donation. In total, the principal prediction is that nobody will contribute. 

Despite this forecast’s accuracy with any given test group, this experiment hardly bears any semblance to the way in which the “public good” is carried out in practice, let alone the way in which the purchasing power of money is created and multiplied. 

This game grossly overstates the value of the so-called “public good” by simply assuming that the headline objective is sufficient grounds for it to be so. Is it at all possible that the alternative investment, or the deferred investment in the form of present savings, may eventually further the “public good” by market transactions not explicitly carrying the “public good” title? 

This game falls devastatingly short in explaining the means by which the investment would multiply, let alone the way by which money empowers interests and actively incentivizes and orchestates the mechanics of the market, by which individuals coordinate directly and indirectly in the fulfillment of their own respective agendas, the total expression of which forms the only up-to-date and accurate expression of the so-called “public good.” 

If nothing else, the outcomes derived from this game highlight the propensity of human beings to be attitudinally risk-averse with their money. Ultimately, this game promises an infinite multiplication of monetary value if only the participants will overcome the statistical biases which impede the realization of their advanced collective good. 

If this were self-evidently the case that the “public good” here were so calculated and tested an investment, how might privatization of this good sterilize its fruits? Might this game then evolve to permit self-interested and privy investors to buy a real stake in this supposed gold mine? As it turns out, players in this game demonstrate a decreased willingness to contribute as they repeat the game, dropping from the usual 50% to near zero. 

One crucial spin, however, on the same experiment weighs considerably on the direction of outcomes. After ten rounds of play, the subjects are informed that they will participate again for another ten rounds with the same cast of players. 

With a more sophisticated understanding of the game and with a more intense sensitivity to the ramifications of their individual actions and their attending influences on the group, the individuals became more willing to contribute. 

These individuals essentially become what is known as conditional cooperators, actors who are willing to cooperate if a critical mass of others have already committed. 

Short of demonstrating the folly of human action, this experiment brilliantly exposes a gaping hole in the precepts of socialist, communist or generally statist leanings: governance is most powerful, responsive and cooperative at the most local level.   

Comments

Popular posts from this blog

America's Civil War: Not "Civil" and Not About Slavery

Virtually the entirety of South and Central America, as well as European powers Britain, Spain and France, peacefully abolished slavery — without war — in the first sixty years of the nineteenth century. 

Why, then, did the United States enter into a bloody war that cost over half of the nation’s wealth, at least 800,000 lives and many hundreds of thousands more in casualties? 

The answer: the War Between the States was not about slavery. 

It was a war of invasion to further empower the central government and to reject state sovereignty, nullification of unconstitutional laws, and the states’ rights to secession. 

It was a war that would cripple the South and witness the federal debt skyrocket from $65 million in 1860 to $2.7 billion in 1865, whose annual interest alone would prove twice as expensive as the entire federal budget from 1860.

It was a war that would blur the lines and jurisdictions between sovereign states, that would indiscriminately sacrifice the founding principles etched …

The Evils of Facebook in the War Against Reason

Facebook is one of the greatest frauds whereby thoughtless friends share or tacitly embrace ideas which, in doing so, adds personal, relatable flair to messages being distributed from largely unknown reporters. 

In effect, these friends then subject a wider community to the thought that since their friends are supportive of such ideas, then they ought to carry some merit or authenticity. 

Facebook commits a great disservice to communication, serving primarily to subject meaningful dialogue to inherently-binary measures of laudability or contemptibility. 

Whereas scientific evaluation serves to extract emotion, Facebook serves to embolden the fallacy-ridden supposition that fact follows fanfare, that truth trails trendiness, and that democratic participation (by way of “likes” or “shares”) can reliably support truth or sustainably produce virtue.

What's more, Facebook and other social media sites tend also to further the fallacy that the last breath, or more precisely the final keystro…

One of Every Three American Adults is a Criminal

Earlier today, the Wall Street Journal posted an article on the growing epidemic of criminal records. The article reports that nearly one out of every three American adults has a criminal record — a statistic corroborated by the Federal Bureau of Investigation, whose records show 77.7 million individuals on file in the organization's master criminal database. Is this an indication of a society which is becoming more violent and criminal, or of one which is becoming ever-populated with needless and overreaching laws, ordinances, and regulations? In a country whose growing majority depends upon government for salary or entitlements, this is indeed the mechanism through which the dependency is enabled. Some are apparently more than willing to surrender increments of freedom for the promise of free stuff.    

Along with the extensive and pervasive development of laws in the United States, their execution has become more vile and horrid; and the experience of police brutality, along wit…